Economics of pricing for brand name drugs:
Profit maximizing choice of \(p, q\):
New profit maximizing choice of \(p, q\):
\[\frac{p^{*}_{c}}{p^{*}_{nc}} = \frac{\frac{1}{2} (\frac{a}{\alpha}+c)}{\frac{a+c}{2}} = \frac{1}{\alpha}\]
Key Points:
Firm 1: \[p_{1}^*(p_{2}) = \frac{a + cp_{2} + mc_{1}}{2b + 1}\] Firm 2: \[p_{2}^*(p_{1}) = \frac{a + cp_{1} + mc_{2}}{2b + 1}\]
Key Points:
Equating the two best response functions to solve for equilibrium prices:
\[\begin{align*} p_{1}^* &= \frac{a(2b+1) + c(a + mc_{2}) + mc_{1}(2b+1)}{2b+1 - c^2} \\ p_{2}^* &= \frac{a(2b+1) + c(a + mc_{1}) + mc_{2}(2b+1)}{2b+1 - c^2} \end{align*}\]
Key Points:
Monopoly Price (previously derived): \[p_{m} = \frac{a + mc_{m}}{2b}\]
Comparison:
Unique drugs with patent protection:
Under these circumstances, there is little opportunity for a purchaser to stimulate competition among manufacturers. Manufacturers are roughly free to set launch prices, they rarely discount those prices, and purchasers and price takers.
Differentiated drugs with imperfect substitutes:
This stage represents the lion’s share of the market at any given time…Depending on how similar the drugs are…organized purchasers have the ability to either switch patients in a medially appropriate way…or at least start new patients on a preferred drug…This is the area where formularies can be applied for the greatest effect on overall costs.